| |
| |
Director of the University of California Energy Institute and a professor of
business at the Haas School of Business, Borenstein also is on the board of
governors of the California Power Exchange. Borenstein, who is not opposed to
deregulating the energy markets, says that politics overshadowed sound policy
when California's plan was drafted.
| | | | |
... You're not opposed to deregulation, is that correct?
No, not at all. I worked at the Civil Aeronautics Board during airline
deregulation and I've seen that up close. It was done carefully and
thoughtfully, with the regulators and deregulators thinking through carefully
what incentive of each player in the market would be, and how each player,
trying to make as much money as they can, would respond to various rules.
Then what's wrong in this system?
What happened in electricity deregulation is that people who designed the
deregulation didn't think through the incentives carefully. So when outsiders
like us pointed out, "You know, a firm in that position could jack the price
way up," the response often was, "Well, that's never happened before." Well,
of course it's never happened before--we haven't deregulated the market yet.
So I think what happened is that a group of people who had operated in a quiet,
regulated environment for years and years got blindsided by market forces.
And the impact of this is going to spread nationally from California. It
already has.
It depends very much on whether the other states are going to learn the lesson
from California. There are some signs that they're learning the right
lesson, but there're also plenty of signs they're learning the wrong lessons
from California. ...
... Do you see similar prices for electricity spreading nationally this
summer?
Not this summer. This summer, most of the country is still going to be in
reasonably good supply shape. But it depends very much on how hot the summer
is, and what the conditions are at the various power plants.
For instance, the Northwest right now has suffered a severe drought during this
winter, and there isn't going to be much hydroelectric production. That could
very much hurt the entire western grid. The New York area has some bottlenecks
where they can't get enough power into particular areas such as New York City,
which very well could drive up the wholesale prices in those markets.
Whether that shows up in the retail prices depends entirely on the state
regulators and whether they let it go through. In California, we haven't let
it go through, and that's been a real mistake.
So the villain in California, from your point of view, is the California
Public Utilities Commission?
CPUC, no question about it. They blew it by not allowing price
increases earlier. That could have prevented some of the financial crises that
the utilities are now in, which has led to a whole other set of problems, and
it would have encouraged some conservation.
They say the prices were mandated by the legislature--that they were fixed
for five years, so they didn't really have a choice.
That's not accurate, because there's a lot of room for interpretation about
when exactly they would allow the prices to go up. Although, in their defense,
in San Diego everyone agreed that the prices were legally allowed to be passed
through, and they were passed through during the summer of 2000. The
legislature responded by turning around and immediately capping them again.
The legislature obviously also didn't have a stomach for letting these prices
go through. Raising retail rates is not the whole answer, but not
raising retail rates has been clearly part of the problem.
The fundamental question that's been raised by [California Governor Gray
Davis' energy advisor], Mr. [David] Freeman, and by
other people is that everyone needs electricity, and it's obviously perishable.
It's not the same as any other commodity; and if you just let it out there in
the marketplace, unregulated, it's going to be a disaster, especially for
people who know how to manipulate the market. ...
That's one of the wrong conclusions that is drawn from California: that
deregulation can't work; that electricity is so different that markets would
never work in electricity. It is definitely the case that electricity is a
much harder product to deregulate than most. But California's approach to
deregulation didn't work. It was not carefully thought through. It was sort
of sloppy policy-by-analogy to other things that had been done, and it didn't
work. That doesn't mean that electricity deregulation can't work.
Mr. Freeman is a lifelong manager of public power organizations, so his
interest obviously is in the public power side. I think that people who are
more neutral on whether it should be a public or private organization
see that we made a lot of mistakes in California, but you really can organize a
market that will work more efficiently.
Is there an efficient marketplace for electricity in the United
States?
Pennsylvania is working a lot better than we are now. They haven't fully
solved their problems either. They still need to make changes in their market
to have it work more efficiently. But they have not seen the extremely high
bills for consumers that we're going to eventually have to pay here.
But Pennsylvania is not in a situation of scarcity.
They're not in a situation of as much scarcity as California is. ...
And they have rate caps.
Well, so do we.
Right. But they also have rate caps in the wholesale market.
And so do we, or we did until very recently. But it wasn't the end of the rate
caps that caused this problem. Even if we had kept the rate caps, we'd still
be in deep trouble right now. The problem occurred when utilities were buying
throughout the summer at high, [albeit] capped, prices and selling at much,
much lower prices. And the reason the prices in the wholesale market were so
high is because the structure of the wholesale market was such that the sellers
could exercise market power.
But the California Public Utilities Commission would turn around and say,
"We couldn't control wholesale prices. That wasn't our job. We went to the
people who do that and they did nothing."
That's right. The California Public Utilities Commission could only have
responded on the retail side, though if they had responded on the retail side
and allowed rates to go up to reflect these costs, there would have been a
decrease in demand. And that decrease in demand would have helped to drive
down wholesale prices.
On the wholesale side, what we could have done back in 1998 was to structure
the deregulated market, so that the firms who were selling power weren't as
large as they are. We have a firm in California that sells 8 percent of the
power in the state; it has 8 percent of the capacity in the state. ... There
are a bunch that are between 6 percent and 8 percent. At the time, that seemed
like a really small share, though some of us were pointing out that, even with
6 percent to 8 percent of the market, on a hot summer day, the system operators
absolutely need you running; and if the system operator absolutely needs your
plant running, you can ask for any price you want.
So it was clear that, even with that deregulation, we were likely to see market
power. Many of us pointed that out. There were things that could have been
done at the time that weren't done which would've greatly reduced the problem.
One would have been to spin the plants off into smaller companies so that no
company, for instance, had more than 1,000 megawatts of capacity. Another
would have been the utilities could have retained ownership of those power
plants, which is what happened for the most part in Pennsylvania. And another
is that they could have spun them off, but signed long-term contracts to buy
the power back at reasonable prices. They didn't do any of those things.
... So a deregulated market doesn't necessarily mean a competitive
market?
A deregulated market doesn't necessarily mean a market with no antitrust
intervention. Antitrust intervention is for the purpose of maintaining a
competitive market. Had we required the utilities to spin off those plants
into small companies, we would have had a much more competitive market.
The FERC was supposed to be the referee on prices, right?
The FERC is supposed to make sure that prices are just and reasonable in
the wholesale electricity market. The FERC has not done its job. They, by and
large, were uninterested in reviewing and carefully thinking about whether this
market would work. And then when it became clear that it didn't work, even to
FERC, who in November said the prices were not just and reasonable, their
response was to say, "Yes, but we're not going to do anything about it."
What's that all about?
The [current] chairman of the FERC is a person who believes very deeply
in markets, regardless of the facts.
But the past chairman?
The past chairman was also of that type. He seemed to not believe that the
FERC really needed to worry about prices in these markets.
Democrat or Republican?
I don't think that that philosophy is strictly only associated with one party.
There's no question that the Clinton administration would have liked to see
more intervention and pressured FERC, but FERC is an independent regulatory
agency. There's a limited amount that the president can do to pressure such an
agency into specific actions.
The president of the United States couldn't have influenced FERC by
appointment, or by just in bully pulpit, concerning what was going on?
There was a lot of pressure towards the end of the administration to do exactly
that, and it wasn't very successful.
So FERC took it upon themselves to stay out of the fray?
They went further than staying out of the fray. They stayed out of the fray
and they blocked attempts by the California Independent System
Operator to control prices and to take actions that would have helped.
What's the rationale behind that?
I'm not a political scientist, and I'm not sure why these people act the way
they do. The chairman of the FERC now is somebody who doesn't really
understand economics and doesn't really understand how businesses operate. In
many speeches very recently, he's said, "You have to just let the market work,"
which is of more religion than understanding of economics. In any market in
the United States, we don't just "let the market work." Every market is
regulated to some extent by antitrust laws, by health and safety laws, etc.
The question is, how much intervention should there be? And that, when done
right, is a careful policy question, and not one that can be addressed by
campaign slogans.
... The FERC has a history of being a legal-oriented regulatory agency,
where the legal process matters much more than good policymaking. They do have
some economists on staff at the FERC, but they actually don't pay any attention
to them. The decisions have been made by the commissioners who, by and large,
have very little training and history in the energy business or in economics,
and by high-ranking lawyers, who also don't seem to understand how markets
work, which isn't very surprising. Up until very recently, most of what they
regulated wasn't very market-oriented, so they didn't really understand markets
and they, for the most part, didn't need to. In the electricity business, that
was particularly true. ...
The problem is we're now moving toward the market-oriented industry, and they
still don't understand how markets work. So they make claims, for instance,
like, "Price caps will discourage investments." Well, that's absolutely right.
If price caps are set too low, they will discourage investments. But as any
economist knows, there's a level at which they would discourage investment.
And price caps that are higher than that won't discourage investment, and
actually can improve the operation of industry.
So the FERC could have intervened and stopped this crisis from
happening?
The FERC could have intervened and certainly lessened the crisis. I think
that, to completely avoid the problems ... we really needed to have a retail
price increase in California as well, and we haven't seen that. And that's not
the first jurisdiction. The first jurisdiction is at the wholesale level.
We needed both of them acting rationally?
That's right. The FERC has dropped the ball on the wholesale market, and the
California Public Utilities Commission has dropped the ball on the retail
market....
What's the lesson here? You've been right, but it doesn't make any
difference.
Well, the lesson is that you need policymakers who are really interested in
getting policy right, and I think that politics has overridden good policy in a
lot of cases. The other lesson is that deregulating a market really requires
very careful understanding of how that market works, not simply blind devotion
to the market process and deregulation.
Many of these problems were completely foreseeable--not all of them. The price
of natural gas going through the roof was not at all foreseeable. That is, if
you look back in 1998 at the future's price of natural gas, it looked like
$2.00 or $2.50 for a million BTUs, out for years to come. That is, most people
thought the price of natural gas would remain quite low. It was a surprise to
virtually everyone that the price of natural gas suddenly spiked up last
summer.
Why would that happen?
The U.S. economy continued growing very strongly, while the supply of natural
gas did not grow, which is what happens when prices are very low. There's not
much economic incentive to explore. Now the prices have gone up. There're a
whole lot of people out there exploring for new natural gas, which is why the
best forecasts of the future of natural gas prices, which are from the futures
market where natural gas is traded, is that the price is going to go down.
It's not going to go down quickly to anywhere near the old level, but starting
from about $2.50, it went up almost $10.00. It's now about $5.00, and probably
a year of two from now, the best guess is going to be around $4.00. ...
At the California border, it's four or five or ten times that.
No, at the California border right now, it's probably two or three times
higher, and that's still a problem. We still are having a problem with the
transportation of natural gas to the West Coast. Some people argue that
there's just a shortage of capacity to transport natural gas from Louisiana to
California. Other people argue that the owners of the pipeline are
systematically manipulating the capacity so that you can't get as much gas out
to California in order to keep the prices high in California.
And if I told you there are documents on file at the FERC that show that El
Paso Gas uses the words, "manipulate the physical spread," as to how they're
going to make money off that pipeline capacity, what would that say to
you?
Well, that would certainly raise my suspicions that they have taken actions in
order to reduce supply in California and raise the price. I wouldn't be
certain of that, but that would be probably my first interpretation. I'd want
to see the documents.
... The regulated market in California, before deregulation ... If I take
you back again to what you said about 1995 in the regulated marketplace--with
the exception of some problems, such as nuclear power plants--you had a stable
surplus capacity. Those companies were all making money.
The regulated environment, for the most part, worked. But it worked in a very
inefficient way in terms of the amount of capacity we built, and it worked in a
way that gave us much higher prices than many people thought, and still think,
were really necessary. So the regulated environment, while stable, was
probably not as efficient as it could be. The goal was to get a more efficient
industry through market forces.
I still believe that is a possible goal, but it has to be done through careful
thought, not through blind devotion to simply deregulating the market, throwing
the doors open and walking out. And, unfortunately, that's what the federal
regulators have viewed as their role in this market. ... You can get a much
better [deregulated] system than we've gotten, and I've given you examples of
how you could have done it. You can make sure that there aren't firms that are
so large that they can exercise market power. You can require firms to, say,
buy a lot of capacity to sell the power on long-term contracts. There are many
things you can do to have a less regulated marketplace that is potentially more
efficient.
In fact, you can continue to regulate all the generation that exists, but then
new generations would be unregulated or less regulated. Then you would give
incentives for new firms to come into the market, while still making sure that
the current generation is priced reasonably.
So you don't believe that you could get enough generation just by simply
guaranteeing people a just and reasonable rate of return?
Absolutely, you can get enough generation. That's what we did for 50 years and
it worked fine. It's just that we had higher prices than were necessary and we
built more plants than were necessary. We were building plants so that we had
130 percent of peak demand, 30 percent more than we would likely need. There
are real environmental consequences to doing that. They are building plants
that sometimes are running for two days a year. It seems like there are
efficient ways to operate. For instance, you could have prices that vary at
the peak time to discourage usage when the system's tight. By doing so, you
might be able to avoid building some of those piker plants. That's something
that could have even been done in a regulation, but it never was.
No. But in hindsight now, it sounds to me what you're saying is, "A
modified form of regulation in a sort of free market."
Do you think the airline is a free market?
Not really.
Well, that's a deregulated market. There are still rules. There are lots of
rules about how they can operate. We haven't said, "We deregulated the
airline, therefore you can do anything you want. Sure, if you want to hire
somebody who's never flown a plane before, that's OK." No, we still regulate
the airline industry. We regulate the way they use airports; we regulate them
on safety grounds; we still have antitrust; we review mergers; we do all of
those things.
... What is your reaction to, let's say, the philosophy of a company
like Enron and Ken Lay, who tells us that everything would be fine if we could
get rid of all of the regulation that's in our way; that the market will take
care of everything?
If we got rid of all regulation, the next few years would be such a massive
transfer of wealth from consumers to companies like those owned by Ken
Lay that the voters would never stand for it. We aren't going to have a
complete deregulation anymore than we completely deregulated the airline
industry or trucking or securities or the natural gas industry. All of the
industries still have regulation. ...
...What is the role of a company like Enron, because of their phenomenal
growth in the last five to ten years?
Enron's a great company. They actually were the ones who learned early on to
hedge risk for various parties that had risk in energy markets by taking both
sides of a trade. That is, they would say, "Oh, you're worried about the price
of gas you're going to buy in a while? We'll sell it to you at a fixed price."
And then they would go to some seller and say, "You're worried about getting a
good price for the gas you're going to sell? We'll buy it from you at a fixed
price." Then they would balance those two positions, and they take a little
something for hedging that risk. So they actually are providing real service
in doing that.
They've also figured out that they can do other things that will potentially
change the price of natural gas and, just like in electricity, those sorts of
positions can be extremely profitable. That's true, by the way, in lots of
commodity markets, and we have regulation in lots of those commodity markets.
...
Do you understand the average person look at something like Enron and what
goes on there on their trading floor, and says, "Well, these people are just
skimming money out of the process, out of the market, on something we all
need." Where's the value?
You can say that about people who trade any commodity. You can say that about
people who trade stocks on the New York Stock Exchange. ...
In the electricity market, you say that the regulator is out to lunch. He
doesn't believe in it.
And that's part of where the problems come from. The regulator, in this case,
does not fully understand how the market works, and as a result, hasn't really
been doing their job....
David Freeman says to us, "Look around the
country. Where are the lights on and the rates low? Wherever there's public
power."
And where has the federal government been subsidizing power for a long time?
Wherever there's public power. So you have to ask, "What is the reason for low
rates in those areas? What is the reason that there are aluminum smelters in
the Northwest? Because there's low, subsidized public power." The federal
government built those dams. We could do that everywhere. ...
What we've seen in the West with deregulation is that a lot of the municipal
utilities have done well. The reason they've done well is not because they're
municipal utilities; it's because they own generation. Any company that owned
generation made out. LADWP, the Los Angeles Department of Water and Power, has
done extremely well under deregulation, because they happen to own a lot of
power plants.
Shasta, which is a public utility up in northern California, has had to double
its rates. Shasta's had to raise its rates by 50 percent because they had not bought
enough power and they did not have enough generation. The difference is not
whether they're public or not. The difference is whether they had covered
their position, or if they had enough power locked in for the future. ...
There are studies that say that no matter how you do it, deregulation is not
going to wind up with cost savings for consumers.
These studies are probably right, in terms of the operational efficiency of a
given set of power plants. That is, once you have a certain number of power
plants on the ground, running them in an integrated fashion is more easily and
effectively done in a single utility. The savings that potentially come about
in a deregulated market are in the investment in new power plants--getting
efficient investments, and avoiding the costs when bad decisions are
made....
The other potential savings from deregulation is through better pricing of
electricity. This could also have happened under regulation, but it never has.
The reality is that the cost of producing electricity changes hour to hour, and
our electricity rates don't reflect that. We have no more incentive to save on
a hot summer afternoon than in the middle of the night. That's just a dumb
way to price electricity at the retail level, while we could change that
through real time pricing of electricity. ...
Every market that's been deregulated in electricity has seen abuse--in the
Midwest, in PJM in Pennsylvania, in the Northeast.
No question about it, every market has had problems. That's not a reason that
a market can't do better than the regulated structure. The regulated structure
also had problems. We can come up with plenty of examples of abuse and of
inefficiency under regulation. The right question to be asking is, is it
possible to construct a deregulated or less regulated market that will operate
more efficiently than the old regulatory structure? I think that's still an
important question to pursue. But we've learned a lot about it from
California, and it's not nearly as easy as people once thought it was. ...
home - california - my bill - new business - regulation - the future - new york times reports
video - interviews - glossary - discussion - synopsis - press - tapes & transcripts - credits
FRONTLINE - wgbh - pbs online
power lines photo ©2001 entropy media/images
web site copyright WGBH educational foundation
|